social change, in
sociology, the alteration of mechanisms within the social structure,
characterized by changes in cultural symbols, rules of behaviour, social
organizations, or value systems.
Throughout
the historical development of their discipline, sociologists have borrowed
models of social change from other academic fields. In the late 19th century,
when evolution became the predominant model for
understanding biological change, ideas of social change took on an evolutionary
cast, and, though other models have refined modern notions of social change,
evolution persists as an underlying principle.
Other
sociological models created analogies between social change and the West’s technological progress. In the
mid-20th century, anthropologists borrowed from the linguistic theory of structuralism to elaborate an approach to social change
called structural functionalism.
This theory postulated the existence of certain basic institutions (including
kinship relations and division of labour) that determine social behaviour.
Because of their interrelated nature, a change in one institution will affect
other institutions.
Various
theoretical schools emphasize different aspects of change. Marxist theory
suggests that changes in modes of production can lead to changes in class
systems, which can prompt other new forms of change or incite class conflict. A
different view is conflict theory, which operates on a broad base that includes
all institutions. The focus is not only on the purely divisive aspects of
conflict, because conflict, while inevitable, also brings about changes that
promote social integration. Taking yet another approach, structural-functional
theory emphasizes the integrating forces in society that
ultimately minimize instability.
Social
change can evolve from a number of different sources, including contact with
other societies (diffusion), changes in the ecosystem (which can cause the loss
of natural resources or widespread disease),technological change (epitomized by the Industrial Revolution,
which created a new social group, the urban proletariat), and population growth
and other demographic variables. Social change is also spurred by ideological,
economic, and political movements.
The changing social
order
Social change in the broadest sense is
any change in social relations. Viewed this way, social change is an
ever-present phenomenon in any society. A distinction is sometimes made then
between processes of change within the social
structure, which serve in part to maintain the structure, and
processes that modify the structure (societal change).
The specific meaning of social change
depends first on the social entity considered. Changes in a small group may be
important on the level of that group itself but negligible on the level of the
larger society. Similarly, the observation of social change depends on the time span studied; most
short-term changes are negligible when examined in the long run. Small-scale
and short-term changes are characteristic of human societies, because customs
and norms change, new techniques and technologies are invented, environmental
changes spur new adaptations, and conflicts result in redistributions of power.
This universal human potential for
social change has a biological basis. It is rooted in the flexibility and
adaptability of the human species—the near absence of biologically fixed action
patterns (instincts) on the one hand and the enormous capacity for learning,
symbolizing, and creating on the other hand. The human constitution makes
possible changes that are not biologically (that is to say, genetically)
determined. Social change, in other words, is possible only by virtue of
biological characteristics of the human species, but the nature of the actual
changes cannot be reduced to these species traits.
Historical background
Several ideas of social change have
been developed in various cultures and historical periods. Three may be
distinguished as the most basic: (1) the idea of decline or degeneration, or,
in religious terms, the fall from an original state of grace, (2) the idea of
cyclic change, a pattern of subsequent and recurring phases of growth and
decline, and (3) the idea of continuous progress. These three ideas were
already prominent in Greek and Roman antiquity and have characterized Western
social thought since that time. The concept of progress, however, has become
the most influential idea, especially since the Enlightenment movement of the 17th and 18th
centuries. Social thinkers such as Anne-Robert-Jacques
Turgot and the marquis
de Condorcet in France and Adam Smith and John Millar in Scotland advanced
theories on the progress of human knowledge and technology.
Progress was also the key idea in
19th-century theories of social evolution, and evolutionism was the common core shared by the most
influential social theories of that century. Evolutionism implied that humans
progressed along one line of development, that this development was
predetermined and inevitable, since it corresponded to definite laws, that some
societies were more advanced in this development than were others, and that
Western society was the most advanced of these and therefore indicated the
future of the rest of the world’s population. This line of thought has since
been disputed and disproved.
Following a different approach, French
philosopher Auguste
Comte advanced a “law of three stages,” according to which
human societies progress from a theological stage, which is dominated by religion, through a
metaphysical stage, in which abstract speculative thinking is most prominent,
and onward toward a positivist stage, in which empirically based scientific
theories prevail.
The most encompassing theory of social
evolution was developed by Herbert
Spencer, who, unlike Comte, linked social evolution to
biological evolution. According to Spencer, biological organisms and human
societies follow the same universal, natural evolutionary law: “a change from a
state of relatively indefinite, incoherent, homogeneity to a state of
relatively definite, coherent, heterogeneity.” In other words, as societies
grow in size, they become more complex; their parts differentiate, specialize
into different functions, and become, consequently, more interdependent.
Evolutionary thought also dominated
the new field of social and cultural anthropology in the second half of the
19th century. Anthropologists such as Sir
Edward Burnett Tylor and Lewis
Henry Morgan classified contemporary societies on
an evolutionary scale. Tylor postulated an evolution of religious ideas from
animism through polytheism to monotheism. Morgan ranked societies from “savage”
through “barbarian” to “civilized” and classified them according to their
levels of technology or sources of subsistence, which he connected with the
kinship system. He assumed that monogamy was preceded by polygamy and
patrilineal descent by matrilineal descent.
Karl Marx and Friedrich
Engels too were highly influenced by
evolutionary ideas. The Marxian distinctions between primitive communism, the
Asiatic mode of production, ancient slavery, feudalism, capitalism, and
future socialism may be interpreted as a list of stages
in one evolutionary development (although the Asiatic mode does not fit well in
this scheme). Marx and Engels were impressed by Morgan’s anthropological theory
of evolution, which became evident in Engels’s book The Origin of the Family,
Private Property, and the State (1884).
The originality of the Marxian theory
of social development lay in its combination of dialectics and gradualism. In Marx’s view social
development was a dialectical process: the transition from one stage to another
took place through a revolutionary transformation, which was preceded by
increased deterioration of society and intensified class struggle. Underlying
this discontinuous development was the more gradual development of the forces
of production (technology and organization
of labour).
Marx was also influenced by the
countercurrent of Romanticism,
which was opposed to the idea of progress. This influence was evident in Marx’s
notion of alienation, a
consequence of social development that causes people to become distanced from
the social forces that they had produced by their own activities. Romantic
counterprogressivism was, however, much stronger in the work of later
19th-century social theorists such as German sociologist Ferdinand
Tönnies. He distinguished between the community (Gemeinschaft), in which people were bound together by
common traditions and ties of affection and solidarity, and the society (Gesellschaft), in which social relations had
become contractual, rational, and nonemotional.
Émile
Durkheim and Max Weber,
sociologists who began their careers at the end of the 19th century, showed
ambivalence toward the ideas of progress. Durkheim regarded the increasing
division of labour as a basic process, rooted in modern individualism, that
could lead to “anomie,” or lack
of moral norms. Weber rejected evolutionism by arguing that the development of
Western society was quite different from that of other civilizations and therefore
historically unique. The West was characterized, according to Weber, by a
peculiar type of rationality that had brought about modern capitalism, modern
science, and rational law but that also created, on the negative side, a
“disenchantment of the world” and increasing bureaucratization.
The work of Durkheim, Weber, and other
social theorists around the turn of the century marked a transition from
evolutionism toward more static theories. Evolutionary theories were criticized
on empirical grounds—they could be refuted by a growing mass of research
findings—and because of their determinism and Western-centred optimism.
Theories of cyclic change that denied long-term progress gained popularity in
the first half of the 20th century. These included the theory of the Italian
economist and sociologist Vilfredo
Pareto on the “circulation of elites” and
those of Oswald
Spengler and Arnold
Toynbee on the life cycle of civilizations. In
the 1930s and ’40s, Harvard professor Pitirim
Sorokin developed a cyclic theory of cultural
change in the West, describing repetitions of change from the ideational to the
idealistic and sensate and back again.
Although the interest in long-term
social change never disappeared, it faded into the background, especially when,
from the 1920s until the 1950s, functionalism, emphasizing an interdependent
social system, became the dominant paradigm both in anthropology and in
sociology. “Social evolution” was substituted for the more general and neutral
concept of “social change.”
The study of long-term social change
revived in the 1950s and continued to develop through the 1960s and ’70s. Neoevolutionist theories were proclaimed by several
anthropologists, includingRalph
Linton, Leslie
A. White, Julian
H. Steward, Marshall D. Sahlins, and Elman
Rogers Service. These authors held to the idea of social
evolution as a long-term development that is both patterned and cumulative. Unlike
19th-century evolutionism, neoevolutionism does not assume that all societies go
through the same stages of development. Instead, much attention is paid to
variations between societies as well as to relations of influence among them.
The latter concept has come to be known by the term acculturation. In addition, social evolution is not
regarded as predetermined or inevitable but is understood in terms of
probabilities. Finally, evolutionary development is not equated with progress.
Revived interest in long-term social
change was sparked by attempts to explain the gaps between rich and poor
countries. In the 1950s and ’60s, Western sociologists and economists developed modernization theories to help understand the
problems of the so-called underdeveloped
countries. Somemodernization theories have been criticized,
however, for implying that poor countries could and should develop—or
modernize—in the manner of Western societies. Modernization theories have also been
criticized for their lack of attention to international power relations, in
which the richer countries dominate the poorer ones. These relations have been
brought to the centre of attention by more recent theories of international
dependency, typified by the “world capitalist system” described by American
sociologist Immanuel
Wallerstein. His world systems theory, however, has been
attacked for empirical reasons and for its failure to account for the collapse
of Soviet regimes and their subsequent movement toward capitalism and democracy.
Wallerstein’s theory has also drawn criticism for failing to explain
significant Third World economic development such as that seen in South Korea,
Singapore, and Hong Kong.
Patterns of social change
Theories of social change, both old
and new, commonly assume that the course of social change is not arbitrary but
is, to a certain degree, regular or patterned. The three traditional ideas of
social change—decline, cyclic change, and progress—have unquestionably
influenced modern theories. Yet because these theories are not scientifically
determined, they fail to make an explicit distinction between decline and
progress. In fact, the qualities of decline and progress cannot be derived
scientifically (that is, from empirical observations) alone but are instead
identified by normative evaluations and value judgments. If the study of social
change is to be conducted on scientific and nonnormative terms, then, only two
basic patterns of social change can be considered: the cyclic, as identified
above, and the one-directional. Often the time span of the change determines
which pattern is observed.
CYCLIC CHANGE
Much of ordinary social life is
organized in cyclic changes: those of the day, the week, and the year. These short-term cyclic
changes may be regarded as conditions necessary for structural stability. Other
changes that have a more or less cyclic pattern are less predictable. One
example is the business
cycle, a recurrent phenomenon of capitalism, which seems
somewhat patterned yet is hard to predict. A prominent theory of the business
cycle is that of the Soviet economist Nikolay
D. Kondratyev, who tried to show the recurrence of long waves of economic boom and recession on an
international scale. He charted the waves from the end of the 18th century,
with each complete wave comprising a period of about 50 years. Subsequent
research has shown, however, that the patterns in different countries have been
far from identical.
Long-term cyclic changes are addressed
in theories on the birth, growth, flourishing, decline, and death of
civilizations. Toynbee conceived world history in this way in the first volumes of A Study of History (1934–61), as did Spengler in his Decline of the West (1918–22). These theories have been
criticized for conceiving of civilizations as natural entities with sharp
boundaries, thinking that neglects the interrelations between civilizations.
ONE-DIRECTIONAL CHANGE
This type of change continues more or
less in the same direction. Such change is usually cumulative and implies growth
or increase, such as that of population density, the size of organizations, or
the level of production. The direction of the change could, however, be one of
decrease or a combination of growth and decrease. An example of this last
process is what American cultural anthropologist Clifford
Geertz has called “involution,”
found in some agrarian societies when population growth is coupled with a decrease in
per capita wealth. Yet another change may be a shift from one pole to the other
of a continuum—from religious to secular ways of thinking, for example. Such a
change may be defined as either growth (of scientific knowledge) or decline (of
religion).
The simplest type of one-directional
change is linear, occurring when the degree of social change is constant over
time. Another type of social change is that of exponential
growth, in which the percentage of growth is constant over time
and the change accelerates correspondingly. Population growth and production
growth are known to follow this pattern over certain time frames.
A pattern of long-term growth may also
conform to a three-stage S curve. In the first phase the change is slow enough
as to be almost imperceptible. Next thechange accelerates. In the third phase
the rate of change slackens until it approaches a supposed upper limit. The
model of the demographic transition in industrializing countries exhibits this
pattern. In the first (premodern or preindustrial) stage both the birth rate
and the mortality rate are high, and, consequently, the population grows very
slowly; then mortality decreases, and the population grows much faster; in the
third stage both the birth rate and the mortality rate have become low, and
population growth approaches zero. The same model has been suggested, more
hypothetically, for the rates of technological and scientific change.
COMBINED PATTERNS OF CHANGE
Cyclic and one-directional changes may
be observed simultaneously. This occurs in part because short-term change tends
to be cyclic while long-term change tends to follow one direction. For example,
production rates of industrializing countries exhibit the pattern of short-term
business cycles occurring within long-term economic development.
These patterns cannot be applied
simply and easily to social reality. At best, they are approximations of social
reality. Comparing the model with reality is not always possible, because
reliable data are not always available. Moreover, and more important, many
social processes do not lend themselves to precise quantitative measurement.
Processes such as bureaucratization or secularization, for example, can be
defined through changes in a certain direction, but it is hard to reach
agreement on the dimensions to be measured.
It remains to be seen whether
long-term social change in a certain direction will be maintained. The
transformation of medieval society into the Western nations of the 20th century
may be conceived in terms of several interconnected long-term one-directional
changes. Some of the more important of these changes include commercialization,
increasing division of labour, growth of production, formation of
nation-states, bureaucratization, growth of technology and science,
secularization, urbanization,
spread of literacy, increasing geographic and social
mobility, and growth of organizations. Many of these changes
have also occurred in non-Western societies. Most changes did not originate in
the West, but some important changes did, such as the Industrial
Revolution and the rise of capitalism. These
changes subsequently had a strong impact on non-Western societies.
Additionally, groups of people outside western Europe have been drawn into a
global division of labour, with Western nation-states gaining dominance both
politically and economically.
The extent to which these changes are
part of a global long-term social development is the central question of social
evolution. Although knowledge concerning this question is far from complete, some general trends may be
hypothesized. One trend is seen in the technological innovations and advances
in scientific knowledge that have harnessed natural forces for the satisfaction
of human needs. Among these innovations were the use of fire, the cultivation
of plants, the domestication of animals (dating from about 8000 bce),
the use of metals, and the process of industrialization.
These long-term developments, combined with long-term capital accumulation, led
to rising production and paved the way for population growth and increasing
population density. Energy production and consumption grew, if not per capita,
then at least per square mile.
Another trend stems from production
methods based on the division
of labour and social
differentiation. The control of natural forces, and the ensuing
social progress, was achieved only by utilizing the division of labour—and the
corresponding specialization of knowledge—to raise productivity beyond natural
limits. One consequence of this growth of productivity and technological
innovation, however, was social differentiation. More people, in other words,
could specialize in activities that were not immediately necessary for
survival. Growth in the size and density of populations and increases in social
differentiation heightened the interdependence of more and more people over
longer distances. In hunting-and-gathering societies people were strongly
interdependent within their small bands, depending on very little from outside
their groups. In modern times most of the world’s people are linked by networks
of interdependence that span the globe.
These processes are not inevitable in
the sense that they correspond to any “law” of social change. They have had the
tendency, however, to spread whenever they occurred. For example, once the set
of transformations known as the agrarian revolution had taken place anywhere in the world,
their extension over the rest of the world was predictable. Societies that
adopted these innovations grew in size and became more powerful. As a
consequence, other societies had only three options: to be conquered and
incorporated by a more powerful agrarian society, to adopt the innovations, or
to be driven to marginal places of the globe. Something similar might be said
of the Industrial Revolution and other power-enhancing innovations, such as
bureaucratization and the introduction of more destructive weapons. The example
of weapons illustrates that these transformational processes should not be
equated with progress in general.
Explanations of social change
One way of explaining social change is
to show causal connections between two or more processes. This may take the
form of determinism or reductionism,
both of which tend to explain social change
by reducing it to one supposed autonomous and all-determining causal process. A
more cautious assumption is that one process has relative causal priority,
without implying that this process is completely autonomous and
all-determining. What follows are some of the processes thought to contribute
to social change.
NATURAL ENVIRONMENT
Changes in the natural environment may
result from climatic variations, natural disasters, or the spread of disease.
For example, both worsening of climatic conditions and the Black Death epidemics are thought to have
contributed to the crisis of feudalism in 14th-century Europe. Changes in the
natural environment may be either independent of human social activities or
caused by them. Deforestation, erosion, and air pollution belong to the latter
category, and they in turn may have far-reaching social consequences.
DEMOGRAPHIC PROCESSES
Population growth and increasing
population density represent demographic forms of social change. Population
growth may lead to geographic expansion of a society, military conflicts, and
the intermingling of cultures. Increasing population density may stimulate
technological innovations, which in turn may increase the division of labour,
social differentiation, commercialization, and urbanization.
This sort of process occurred in western Europe from the 11th to the 13th
century and in England in the 18th century, where population growth spurred the
Industrial Revolution. On the other hand, population growth may contribute to
economic stagnation and increasing poverty, as may be witnessed in
several Third World countries today.
TECHNOLOGICAL INNOVATIONS
Several theories of social evolution
identify technological innovations as the most important determinants of
societal change. Such technological breakthroughs as the smelting of iron, the
introduction of the plow in agriculture, the invention of the steam engine, and
the development of the computer have had lasting social consequences.
ECONOMIC PROCESSES
Technological changes are often considered
in conjunction with economic processes. These include the formation and
extension of markets, modifications of property relations (such as the change
from feudal lord-peasant relations to contractual proprietor-tenant relations),
and changes in the organization of labour (such as the change from independent
craftsmen to factories). Historical materialism, as
developed by Marx and Engels, is one of the more prominent theories that gives
priority to economic processes, but it is not the only one. Indeed, materialist
theories have even been developed in opposition to Marxism. One of these theories,
the “logic of industrialization” thesis by American
scholar Clark Kerr
and his colleagues, states that industrialization everywhere has similar
consequences, whether the property relations are called capitalist orcommunist.
IDEAS
Other theories have stressed the
significance of ideas as causes of social change. Comte’s law of three stages
is such a theory. Weber regarded religious ideas as important contributors to
economic development or stagnation; according to his controversial thesis, the
individualistic ethic of Christianity, and in particular Calvinism,
partially explains the rise of the capitalist spirit, which led to economic
dynamism in the West.
SOCIAL MOVEMENTS
A change in collective ideas is not
merely an intellectual process; it is often connected to the formation of new social
movements. This in itself might be regarded as a potential cause
of social change. Weber called attention to this factor in conjunction with his
concept of “charismatic leadership.” The charismatic leader, by virtue of the extraordinary
personal qualities attributed to him, is able to create a group of followers
who are willing to break established rules. Examples include Jesus, Napoleon,
and Hitler. Recently, however, the concept of charisma has been trivialized to
refer to almost any popular figure.
POLITICAL PROCESSES
Changes in the regulation of violence,
in the organization of the state, and in international relations may also
contribute to social change. For example, German sociologist Norbert
Elias interpreted the formation of states in
western Europe as a relatively autonomous process that led to increasing
control of violence and, ultimately, to rising standards of self-control.
According to other theories of political revolution, such as those proposed by
American historical sociologist Charles Tilly, the functioning of the state
apparatus itself and the nature of interstate relations are of decisive
importance in the outbreak of a revolution: it
is only when the state is not able to fulfill its basic functions of
maintaining law and order and defending territorial integrity that
revolutionary groups have any chance of success.
Each of these processes may contribute
to others; none is the sole determinant of social change. One reason why
deterministic or reductionist theories are often disproved is that the method
for explaining the processes is not autonomous but must itself be explained.
Moreover, social processes are often so intertwined that it would be misleading
to consider them separately. For example, there are no fixed borders between
economic and political processes, nor are there fixed boundaries between
economic and technological processes. Technological change may in itself be
regarded as a specific type of organizational or conceptual change. The causal
connections between distinguishable social processes are a matter of degree and
vary over time.
Mechanisms of social change
Causal explanations of social change are limited in scope,
especially when the subject of study involves initial conditions or basic
processes. A more general and theoretical way of explaining social change is to
construct a model of recurring mechanisms of social change. Such mechanisms,
incorporated in different theoretical models, include the following.
MECHANISMS OF ONE-DIRECTIONAL CHANGE: ACCUMULATION, SELECTION, AND
DIFFERENTIATION
Some evolutionary theories stress the
essentially cumulative nature of human knowledge. Because human beings are
innovative, they add to existing knowledge, replacing less adequate ideas and
practices with better ones. As they learn from mistakes, they select new ideas
and practices through a trial-and-error process (sometimes compared to the
process of natural
selection). According to this theory, the expansion of
collective knowledge and capabilities beyond a certain limit is possible only
by specialization and differentiation. Growth of technical knowledge stimulates
capital accumulation,
which leads to rising production levels. Population growth also may be
incorporated in this model of cumulative evolution: it is by the accumulation
of collective technical knowledge and means of production that human beings can
increase their numbers; this growth then leads to new problems, which are
solved by succeeding innovation.
MECHANISMS OF CURVILINEAR AND CYCLIC CHANGE: SATURATION
AND EXHAUSTION
Models of one-directional change
assume that change in a certain direction induces further change in the same
direction; models of curvilinear or cyclic change, on the other hand, assume
that change in a certain direction creates the conditions for change in another
(perhaps even the opposite) direction. More specifically, it is often assumed
that growth has its limits and that in approaching these limits the change curve
will inevitably be bent. Ecological conditions such as the availability of
natural resources, for instance, can limit population, economic, and
organizational growth.
Shorter-term cyclic changes are
explained by comparable mechanisms. Some theories of the business cycle, for
example, assume that the economy is saturated periodically with capital
goods; investments become less necessary and less profitable, the rate of investments
diminishes, and this downward trend results in a recession. After a period of
time, however, essential capital goods will have to be replaced; investments
are pushed up again, and a phase of economic expansion begins.
CONFLICT,
COMPETITION, AND COOPERATION
Group conflict has often been viewed
as a basic mechanism of social change, especially of those radical and sudden
social transformations identified as revolutions. Marxists in particular tend
to depict social life in capitalist society as a struggle between a ruling
class, which wishes to maintain the system, and a dominated class, which
strives for radical change. Social change then is the result of that struggle.
These ideas are basic to what sociologist Ralf Dahrendorf has called a conflict
model of society.
The notion of conflict becomes more
relevant to the explanation of social change if it is broadened to include competition between rival groups. Nations, firms,
universities, sports associations, and artistic schools are groups between
which such rivalry occurs. Competition stimulates the introduction and diffusion
of innovations, especially when they are potentially power-enhancing. Thus, the
leaders of non-Western states feel the necessity of adopting Western science
and technology, even though their ideology may be anti-Western, because it is
only by these means that they can maintain or enhance national autonomy and
power.
Additionally, competition may lead to
growth in the size and complexity of the entities involved. The classic example
of this process, as first suggested by Adam Smith, is
the tendency in capitalism toward collusion and the establishment of monopolies
when small firms are driven out of the competitive marketplace. Another example
came from Norbert
Elias, who suggested that western European nation-states were
born out of competitive struggles between feudal lords. Competition also
dominates theories of individualism, in which social change is seen as the
result of individuals pursuing their self-interest. Game theory and other mathematical devices,
however, have shown that individuals acting in their own self-interest will in
certain conditions cooperate with one another and thereby widen the existing
social networks.
TENSION AND ADAPTATION
In structural functionalism, social
change is regarded as an adaptive response to some tension within the social
system. When some part of an integrated social system changes, a tension
between this and other parts of the system is created, which will be resolved
by the adaptive change of the other parts. An example is what the American
sociologist William
Fielding Ogburn has called cultural
lag, which refers in particular to a gap that develops between
fast-changing technology and other slower-paced sociocultural traits.
DIFFUSION OF INNOVATIONS
Some social changes result from the
innovations that are adopted in a society. These can include technological
inventions, new scientific knowledge, new beliefs, or a new fashion in the
sphere of leisure. Diffusion is not automatic but selective; an innovation is
adopted only by people who are motivated to do so. Furthermore, the innovation
must be compatible with important aspects of the culture. One reason for the
adoption of innovations by larger groups is the example set by higher-status
groups, which act as reference groups for other people. Many innovations tend to
follow a pattern of diffusion from higher- to lower-status groups. More
specifically, most early adopters of innovations in modern Western societies,
according to several studies, are young, urban, affluent, and highly educated,
with a high occupational status. Often they are motivated by the wish to
distinguish themselves from the crowd. After diffusion has taken place,
however, the innovation is no longer a symbol of distinction. This motivates
the same group to look for something new again. This mechanism may explain the
succession of fads, fashions, and social movements. (See social
class, social
status.)
PLANNING AND INSTITUTIONALIZATION
OF CHANGE
Social change may result from
goal-directed large-scale social planning. The possibilities for planning by government bureaucracies and other large
organizations have increased in modern societies. Most social planning is
short-term, however; the goals of planning are often not reached, and, even if
the planning is successful in terms of the stated goals, it often has
unforeseen consequences. The wider the scope and the longer the time span of
planning, the more difficult it is to attain the goals and avoid unforeseen or
undesired consequences. This has most often been the case in communist and
totalitarian societies, where the most serious efforts toward integrated and
long-term planning were put into practice. Most large-scale and long-term
social developments in any society are still largely unplanned, yet large-scale
changes resulting from laws to establish large governmental agencies, such as
for unemployment insurance, old-age pensions, or guaranteed medical care, have
produced significant institutional changes in most industrial societies.
Planning implies institutionalization
of change, but institutionalization does not imply planning. Many unplanned
social changes in modern societies are institutionalized; they originate in
organizations permanently oriented to innovation, such as universities and the
research departments of governments and private firms, but their social
repercussions are not controlled. In the fields of science and technology,
change is especially institutionalized, which produces social change that is
partly intended and partly unintended.
Conclusion
The causes of social change are
diverse, and the processes of change can be identified as either short-term
trends or long-term developments. Change can be either cyclic or
one-directional.
The mechanisms of social change can be
varied and interconnected. Several mechanisms may be combined in one
explanatory model of social change. For example, innovation by business might
be stimulated by competition and by government regulation.
To the degree that change processes
are regular and interconnected, social change itself is structured. Since about 1965 there has been a shift in
emphasis from “structure” to “change” in social theory. Change on different
levels—social dynamics in everyday life and short-term transformations and
long-term developments in society at large—has become the focus of much
attention in the study of society.
No comments:
Post a Comment